In learning more about the concept of web
analytics and the increasingly significant role the “byte-crumb trails” that
consumers leave behind as they surf the web, one cannot but consider whether
the information these trails generate will serve as a force that will enhance
the competitive nature of the markets operating in the internet, resulting in
an improvement for the consumers, or if it will be a force that will generate
an increasing asymmetry of information between consumers and suppliers.
Perhaps
our “byte-crumbs” will have different effects depending on the nature of the
businesses in question when operating outside the Internet.
For
example, let’s take shoe stores. Before the Internet, shoe shopping, other than
mail-order catalogs like LL Bean, was mostly a local transaction. With the advent
of the Internet, consumers were empowered to compare prices for the same
product across an entire country – if not the entire World- and purchase the
pair that was more convenient. Moreover, customers were now exposed to a
significantly larger market with access to see competitors’ pricing making the
market extremely transparent and eliminating the local monopoly that the “mom
& pop” shoe store on Main Street may have previously enjoyed in small towns
all over the World. Using the “byte-crumbs” will have little effect other than
understanding where they need to ship and potentially other products that can
be offered based on the demographics of where the shoes have shipped (or been
billed to) and some inference for tastes, as well as defining better strategies
to better route purchasing intent from one shoe store to the other. Yet any
attempt to discriminate prices for a single product based on any information in
the profile would be futile and short lived given the availability of several
other players providing the exact same product or near substitutes. Such an
effect would deepen traits of competitive markets where the asymmetry of
information is significantly reduced.
But, for
example, what happens with not-so-competitive markets, with high barriers of
entry, such as airline operators? Established oligopolies where the
alternatives on routes is more limited than the amount of carriers could use
this information to significantly mark-up prices for the same route, from one
customer to the next by simply using immediately available demographic and
other profiling information such as the operating system, the location the
query is originating from, the type of device (browser toolbars and some
cookies could capture whether the system capabilities, which can be used to
estimate income level, etc.) to discriminate prices. Using a high-end MacBook
Pro to shop for an airline ticket online could signify paying a premium for a
seat on an airplane over someone who is browsing with a Windows XP machine,
given that one device is likely more expensive than the other. In this case,
while the profiling tactics and available information might lead to a better
understanding of different customers’ Willingness to Pay, this information
could – and probably will – be used by providers to “tailor” prices to capture
more of the consumer surplus in each individual transaction since airlines will
not engage in price-wars to acquire customers. In essence, charging more for a
non-differentiated product or service based solely on assumptions based on the
profile. What was once limited to
discriminating business vs. leisure travel can now be fractioned up by as many
dimensions as consumers are sharing through their online movements.
In the
physical world, this type of discrimination could be significantly harder to
do, but with the limited alternatives, consumers are mostly trapped. With the
empowering of the online world and the trails of “byte-crumbs” that deliver
information about how consumers think, their estimated income level and more,
this trait of oligopolies can deepen significantly and allow or near-perfect
price discrimination. However, alternatives have emerged with online ticket
aggregators and travel sites like Expedia, or Priceline which even allows
consumers to “place blind bids” and have vendors provide services that would
usually exceed a consumer’s Willingness To Pay for prices at or below that
mark, but those types of bids have significant risks for both sides (i.e.: non-fulfillment from vendors) or that make the overall transaction a completely different type of operation.
No comments:
Post a Comment